An Opportunity to Reflect on Mexico's Economic Development
Eduardo Turrent is the historian of the Bank of Mexico. This
article is excerpted from a paper delivered at a conference of the
Ludwig von Mises Cultural Institute of Mexico City, September 23–24,
1998, celebrating the publication in Spanish of Ludwig von Mises’s Mexico’s Economic Problems: Yesterday and Today, which was written in 1943 but unpublished until last year. Translated by Bettina Bien Greaves.
Today should be a day of celebration for students, book lovers, and
all who are interested in reflecting on the economic development of
Mexico. Mexico’s Economic Problems by Ludwig von Mises, which Bettina Greaves found in 1997 among Mises’s papers, is truly a treasure.[1]
Although there are obvious differences, it calls to mind musicologist
Alberto Gentili’s rediscovery in the 1920s of the complete works of
Antonio Vivaldi, more than 200 years after the composer’s death. We
economic historians are more fortunate than musicians and music lovers
were, since Mises’s text has reappeared only 25 years after his death.
The monograph by Mises on the Mexican economy is outstanding in many
respects. One particularly important aspect is that it is relevant to
more than just the economic situation he found when he visited in 1942.
Mises was concerned with the long-run historical context; or as one says
nowadays, he focused on fundamental structural change. He was
interested in uncovering the fallacies on which the principal positions
and policies of Mexico’s former socialist regime, as well as all
socialist regimes, were based.
One of the principal points in Mises’s essay was his vote of
confidence for Mexico because of the capabilities of its people and the
progress of the country. As he put it: “It is beyond doubt that the
Mexicans are endowed with the spirit of workmanship. The achievements of
the autochthonous [indigenous] craftsmen and artisans meet with the
admiration of all experts. The workers in the already existing
industrial plants and in the mines are not less efficient than those of
other countries.” And the same may be said with respect to their
entrepreneurial and other skills.
Thus the problem of Mexico’s development was not capital scarcity,
geography (which Mises judged favorably), climate, or geology, even
though the soil “in the greater part of the country is dry and barren.”
Development depends on the application of “an appropriate economic
policy”; that is, a “wise” economic policy aimed at the “establishment
of a durable system resulting in a continuous improvement of the
nation’s well-being.”
Unfortunately, this was not the case in Mexico when Mises wrote this
paper. Nor has it been the case since, especially not from 1970 to 1982,
even if one considers the several forms such a “wise” policy may take.
Attack on Easy Money
Only five or six years after the publication of Keynes’s General Theory,
Mises took a well-aimed shot at the economic policies that stemmed from
the noted English author’s ideas. According to Mises, the “easy money”
policies of the interwar years, policies that tended to generate
inflation, had been based on the doctrines of Lord Keynes, doctrines
that Mises called “fallacious.” To Mises, the Keynesian dictum that “in
the long run we are all dead” was no more than a new version of the
cruel-hearted motto attributed to Madame de Pompadour, “After us, the
deluge.” Thus, every strategy that “is indifferent about the tomorrow
strives after ephemeral success and carelessly sacrifices the future.”
Such strategies must not be considered “progressive, but parasitic.”
Growth may be sustained only by having fundamental policies favorable to
the stability of money and exchange.
Mises said in this study, not without cause, that the monetary
history of Mexico, like that of many other countries, has been “a record
of failures and disasters.” He hit the bull’s-eye when he said that
“Monetary troubles are never the inextricable outcome of conditions
beyond the control of a country’s government. They are always the result
of a deliberate policy,” which, only too often, has been “the result of
erroneous monetary doctrines.” Thus, with a nod to the then-current
financial authorities in Mexico, Mises pointed to the need to return to a
firm path toward stability.
But stability is not a goal in and of itself. “Monetary stability”
must be recognized as a means, “an indispensable requirement for the
formation of capital.” Moreover, the consequences of applying an “easy
money” inflationary policy are, and have been, economic depressions with
millions unemployed and social unrest. “Easy money” policies “result
for a short time in the creation of an artificial boom, but must later
end in a slump and in depression.”
Few of the wise observations, prescriptions, clairvoyant remarks, and
even prophetic visions in Mises’s text appear obsolete, not even his
proposals concerning exchange. Nevertheless, one must remember that this
manuscript was written years before Bretton Woods and more than a
decade before the celebrated article by Milton Friedman, “Fixed vs.
Flexible Exchange Rates” (1953). It should not be surprising that Mises
showed himself in 1942 to be an advocate of the gold standard. However,
one should look at the matter from the perspective of history.
Basically, what Mises wanted was not something radically different from
what Domingo Cavallo introduced in Argentina, fixed exchange with a
monetary policy subject to discipline.[2]
At a time when public deficits have come to be considered virtuous,
Mises insisted on the advantages of fiscal health. He explained clearly
that excessive public spending contributes neither to disposable income
for the masses nor to the supply of social capital. If the public budget
is in disequilibrium, this must be financed either by issuing central
bank credit or by using internal debt. If central bank credit is used to
finance the public debt, it is doubly pernicious because, in addition
to leading to inflation with all its harmful consequences, it affects
the balance of payments and hinders the maintenance of exchange
stability. If internal debt is used to finance the public debt, wealth
is simply withdrawn from the private sector and transferred to the
public sector. Public spending proposals assume, also, that the
government will spend resources better than individuals will. But is
this by any means certain? Withdrawing purchasing power from the private
sector not only reduces the total resources entrepreneurs will have
available to invest, but it may also reduce the income and consumption
of the needy.
It is possible, even likely, that in his Mexican travels under the
guidance of Montes de Oca, Mises became acquainted with the Mexican
historian Daniel Cosio Villegas. Mises’s opinions concerning the
apparent and abundant “natural wealth of Mexico and the chances of its
future prosperity” were contrary to the views then commonly held. But
they were remarkably similar, particularly in emphasis and approach, to
those expressed by Cosio Villegas in his essay “The Legendary Wealth of
Mexico.” Mises’s sharp observations were, and still are,
particularly applicable to the agricultural capabilities of Mexico. To
Mises the natural supply and quality of the land were not insuperable
obstacles. Rather, he looked on agricultural policy, which was rooted in
the heart of the revolutionary ideology, as the obstacle to the
country’s progress.
Mises cited figures to illustrate what he called the harmful effects
“of the agrarian reform of the revolution.” The crops of corn and wheat
had been much less in 1937 than in 1907 and those of beans less than in
1897. Mises saw clearly, as did Manuel Gómez Morín and a few other
illustrious intellects, that in Mexico, as in any other country, the
agricultural sector could not make progress without a clear definition
and absolute respect for the rights of property. The plain fact was that
those rights were not well defined in the arrangement made for common
land. Therefore, land was not only not cultivated with the devotion
required, but investments necessary for the development of the land were
not made either.
The right to property is the necessary condition for all modern
productive activity. Therefore, Mises argued strenuously in 1942 against
the desire of many to look to the Soviet system of agricultural
collectives as the example for Mexico to follow. Granting that, however,
Mises did not object to, and he even looked with favor on, other forms
of collective activity even with the active participation of the state.
For instance, he mentioned cooperatives that could be formed to acquire
farm equipment, seed, and fertilizers, and to cover other expenses. Such
cooperatives could also arrange for leasing machinery, selling farm
produce, and obtaining credits for members. The government could also
help with institutions to promote technological education and
agricultural research. Nevertheless, every individual farmer should be
“the master on his own farm.”[3]
The Demographic Problem
Surely Mises was one of the first visionaries to recognize the
demographic problem from which Mexico has long suffered. Mexico, he
noted, is “a comparatively overpopulated country,” with the surplus
population living in rural areas. The potential productivity of the
country was insufficient to assure a decent standard of living for these
excess people. Therefore, the only viable solution was for industries
to be developed to absorb that excess population. But truly productive
industries could develop only in response to definite commercial
opportunities.
In 1942, Mises called for something that was then strictly taboo,
something that could not be undertaken in Mexico until more than four
decades later: an “open door” trade policy. If the dismantling of our
ancient protectionist structure in recent times provoked no few laments
and rending of garments, imagine the reaction to the Austrian
economist’s proposal in the 1940s, in the midst of the great World War.
Contrary to archaic mercantilist doctrines, Mises looked on imports as
something desirable; he considered the opening of trade as the
indispensable means for obtaining the best possible allocation of
resources. “The advantage derived from foreign trade lies entirely in
importing, not in exporting,” he said. According to Mises, only by
competitive industry emerging in an open environment can manufactured
products be produced at prices that permit living standards in the
country to rise while at the same time generating exports to pay for the
nation’s indispensable imports. The problem, he lamented, is that many
Mexican patriots were “entangled in the neo-mercantilist fallacies” then
in vogue—and I would say still in vogue among many groups.
The whole process of industrialization based on protectionism is
damaging in three ways. First, protection inhibits the agricultural
sector from exporting. Second, it raises the prices of manufactured
consumers goods, which could otherwise be acquired by the rural
inhabitants. And third, because of its high costs, industrialization
based on protectionism prevents the manufactured products from
penetrating international markets. It is true that, given such
industrialization, many people would find employment in the protected
industries. But what they would gain as employees others in other
sectors of the economy would lose through the high cost of the
manufactured articles. In this way any possibility of raising “the
standard of living of the average Mexican” would be lost. Therefore,
Mises concluded, industrialization by means of protection would lead the
nation down a “blind alley” since it would perpetuate the low living
standards of the people.
Although Mises argued for opening up trade gradually, he predicted
that there was no need to fear that, by removing tariff barriers, “any
plant will be forced to discontinue production. Some plants, it is true,
will have to rearrange their lines of production in order to obtain a
higher degree of specialization.” But, to the great surprise of many,
the visiting Austrian recommended opening up trade unilaterally—removing
commercial barriers even though other countries maintained protective
policies without offering commercial reciprocity.
Mises’s expectations about opening the country up to trade were
absolutely correct, as they were in other instances. Although the
Mexican opening was not gradual and the policy adopted was unilateral in
the beginning, practically no failures that could be attributed to that
fact were reported.
Mises explained how the opening up of trade, with all its benefits,
cannot yield its full benefits without a coherent and a compatible wage
policy. Today those who think real wages can be determined by decree or
by employer-employee negotiations still organize in battalions. But
those who are serious know the painful consequences of such a wage
policy; it directly diminishes the competitiveness of enterprises and
employment, and indirectly affects inflation and economic growth. As
Mises expressed it:
There is but one means to raise Mexican wage rates: industrial expansion. Every new plant improves the standard of living of the Mexican masses by creating an additional demand for labor. But industry cannot allow higher wages than such as safeguard the conduct of business. If trade unions are anxious to enforce higher wages, they prevent the establishment of new plants and the expansion of existing plants. They succeed, it is true, in raising wage rates for a comparatively small group of workers; but they force, on the other hand, hundreds of thousands to remain in agricultural occupations, in which their income is extremely low, i.e., much lower than it would be if they could find industrial jobs.
Mises was absolutely clairvoyant in suggesting in 1942 that private
initiative should participate in the production of petroleum, the
management of the railroads, and the generation of electricity. He was
also right in insisting that unless investment and production have
confidence, they cannot thrive and thus cannot contribute to economic
progress.
Railroads, Electricity, and Petroleum
More than half a century after Mises’s visit, his recommendation with
respect to the railroads is becoming a reality. In the case of
investment in the field of electricity, there are now indications that
private capital will be permitted greater participation in the future.
As for the production of petroleum, we are still far from a decision;
some isolated voices suggest only occasionally, rather timidly, that the
matter be reconsidered.
Further, Mises was several decades ahead in predicting what would
happen in Mexico between 1970 and 1976 with respect to cooperativism. In
that six-year period the management of cooperatives in some sectors,
like that of fishing, was entirely given up. The results had been very
disappointing; they fulfilled to the letter what Mises had written years
before. “No serious economist believes that a cooperative society could
successfully compete with private enterprises. The experiments have
resulted in complete failure.” This, he said, applied especially in the
field of industrial production.
One of the themes emphasized in Mises’s essay is the importance of
maintaining the confidence of investors in order to improve the
country’s material welfare. In Mexico’s Economic Problems there
are more than ten references to this. On this point Mises was
absolutely positive: “What Mexico needs most is capital, either foreign
or domestic. The repudiation of the national debt and the expropriation
of foreign investments deter the foreign capitalist. The methods of
taxation prevent the accumulation of domestic capital.”
The investor, domestic or foreign, fears every attack on property
rights, lack of public safety, and arbitrariness. Strictly speaking,
when we consider the situation, confiscatory taxation is aggression
against the right of property. According to Mises, very high taxes
“paralyze the spirit of entrepreneurship.” Therefore, he recommended
that Mexico distance itself from a “suicidal” tax policy of this kind.
Taxes should never discourage saving or the accumulation of capital. In
this same vein, personal and entrepreneurial income that is invested
should be taxed at a lower rate.
Mises’s essay is enlightening and clear; it refutes fallacies,
destroys myths, is analytical, and advisory. When it was first written
and made available in Mexico, it had practically no effect; in fact it
was forgotten. Why? I venture a few theories.
First, his views were in opposition in many regards to the most
widely accepted ideas of the time and the years to follow. Moreover,
there was resistance from the powerful groups that were surely
disturbed, or would have been disturbed, by this text. International
experience reveals that one of the great obstacles to undertaking
reforms is special-interest groups. And Mises’s paper touched directly
on many of them, especially syndicalism, the agrarian reform
bureaucracy, the administrators of public enterprises that would be
dismantled, the industrial beneficiaries of protectionist measures, the
clientele of subsidized organizations, and even the teachers who were
preaching in the schools and universities “the religion of étatism.” In
this connection, Chapter XI of Mises’s essay, “Education,” is
recommended.
However, as Keynes said, the ideas of economists and social
philosophers are more powerful than generally believed. There is a
tendency to exaggerate the power of special interests as compared with
the gradual penetration of ideas. And something that Keynes did not say,
but which I firmly believe, is that in the long run, correct ideas will
succeed in asserting themselves over the fallacies and the economic
deceits.
No comments:
Post a Comment