Richard
W. Fisher
“Not to Be Used
Externally, but Also Harmful if Swallowed”: Projecting the Future of the
Economy and Lessons Learned from Texas and Mexico
Remarks before the Dallas Regional Chamber of Commerce
Dallas, Texas
March 5, 2012
Remarks before the Dallas Regional Chamber of Commerce
Dallas, Texas
March 5, 2012
I have been asked to
speak about the economy. I am going to take a different approach than
is typical for a Federal Reserve speech. I’ll eschew making the
prototypical forecast, except to note that from my perch at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, I presently see that: a.) On balance, the data
indicate improving growth and prospects for job creation in 2012.
However, the outlook is hardly “robust” and remains constrained by the
fiscal and regulatory misfeasance of Congress and the executive branch
and is subject to a now well-known, and likely well-discounted, list of
possible exogenous shocks—the so-called “tail risks”—posed by possible
developments of different sorts in the Middle East, Europe, China and
elsewhere. And b.) While price stability is being challenged by the
recent run-up in gasoline prices—which has yet to be reflected in the
personal consumption expenditure and consumer price indexes but may well
make for worrisome headlines when February data are released—the
underlying trend has been converging toward the 2 percent long-term
goal formally adopted by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) at
its last meeting.[1]
As to the outlook
envisioned by the entire FOMC, you might wish to consult the forecasts
of all 17 members, which include those of yours truly, that were made
public after the January meeting—though I think a puckish footnote
appended to the internal document laying out a component of the
December 1966 FOMC forecast might still apply: “Not to be used
externally, but also harmful if swallowed.”[2]
Speaking of harmful if
swallowed, I might add that I am personally perplexed by the continued
preoccupation, bordering upon fetish, that Wall Street exhibits
regarding the potential for further monetary accommodation—the
so-called QE3, or third round of quantitative easing. The Federal
Reserve has over $1.6 trillion of U.S. Treasury securities and almost
$848 billion in mortgage-backed securities on its balance sheet. When
we purchased those securities, we injected money into the system. Most
of that money and more has accumulated on the sidelines: More than $1.5
trillion in excess reserves sit on deposit at the 12 Federal Reserve
banks, including the Dallas Fed, for which we pay private banks a measly
25 basis points in interest. A copious amount is being harbored by
nondepository financial institutions, and another $2 trillion is
sitting in the cash coffers of nonfinancial businesses.
Trillions of dollars
are lying fallow, not being employed in the real economy. Yet financial
market operators keep looking and hoping for more. Why? I think it may
be because they have become hooked on the monetary morphine we
provided when we performed massive reconstructive surgery, rescuing the
economy from the Financial Panic of 2008–09, and then kept the
medication in the financial bloodstream to ensure recovery. I
personally see no need to administer additional doses unless the patient
goes into postoperative decline. I would suggest to you that, if the
data continue to improve, however gradually, the markets should begin
preparing themselves for the good Dr. Fed to wean them from their
dependency rather than administer further dosage.
I am well aware of the
salutary effect of accommodative monetary policy on the equity and
fixed-income markets—remember, I am the only member of the FOMC who
used to be on the other side. My firms’ record of substantially
outperforming the equity and fixed-income indexes over a prolonged
period before I hung up my investment business and entered public
service in 1997 was achieved by focusing on the long-term fundamentals
of the real economy and the underlying value of the securities we
purchased or sold—not by depending on central bank largesse. Counting
on the Fed to perpetually float returns is a mug’s game.
From my present
perspective on the side of the angels, as a member of the policymaking
team on the FOMC, I believe adding to the accommodative doses we have
applied rather than beginning to wean the patient might be the
equivalent of medical malpractice. Having never before pursued this
course of healing, we run the risk of painting ourselves further into a
corner from which we do not know the costs of exiting. It is my opinion
that we should run that risk only in the most dire of circumstances,
and I presently do not see those circumstances obtaining.
So much for
forecasting and monetary policy. Let me now walk you through an
overview of the Texas economy to set the stage for a broader discussion
of what I believe continues to bedevil a lasting recovery and more
efficient job creation in the United States.
I will use some slides to illustrate key points.
The National
Bureau of Economic Research, the arbiter of when recessions begin and
end, dates the onset of the Great Recession as December 2007. The
economic performance of Texas since December 2007 can be summarized
with the chart projected on the screen. It depicts employment growth in
the 12 Federal Reserve districts. In the Eleventh Federal Reserve
District―or the Dallas Fed’s district—96 percent of economic production
comes from the 25.7 million people of Texas. As you can see by the red
line, we now have more people at work than we had before we felt the
effects of the Great Recession. All told in 2011, Texas alone created
212,000 jobs.[3]
Only two other states can claim they surpassed previous peak employment levels: Alaska and North Dakota.
Readers of this speech abroad―say, in
Washington or New York―might think our growth last year came only from
the burgeoning oil and gas patch. They would be right to describe it as
burgeoning: 30,000 jobs were added in oil and gas and the related
support sector last year. Texas now produces 2.1 million barrels of oil
per day, the same amount as Norway; we produce 6.7 trillion cubic feet
of natural gas a year, only slightly less than Canada.[4]
With 25 percent of
U.S. refinery capacity and 60 percent of the nation’s petrochemical
production located in Texas, we most definitely benefit from both
upstream and downstream energy production.
And yet other sectors
gained more jobs than the oil and gas sector and its support functions
in 2011: 58,000 jobs were added in professional and business services,
nearly 46,000 in education and health services and more than 41,000 in
leisure and hospitality. Manufacturing―which accounts for approximately
8 percent of total Texas employment―added over 27,000 jobs.
All told, the private
sector in Texas expanded by 266,400 jobs in 2011, while the public
sector contracted by 54,800, due primarily to layoffs of
schoolteachers. In sum, Texas payrolls grew 2 percent, significantly
above the national rate of 1.3 percent.
This performance is
not unique to last year. As you can see from this graph of
nonagricultural employment growth by Federal Reserve district going
back to January 1990, the Eleventh District has outperformed the nation
on the job front for over two decades. Note the slope of the top line,
which depicts job growth in the Eleventh District compared with each
of the other districts and, importantly, relative to employment growth
for the U.S. as a whole―denoted by the black line, the seventh one down.
As was pointed
out in high relief by the media when a certain Texas governor was
briefly in the hunt for his party’s presidential nomination, we do have
some serious deficiencies in the Lone Star State. We have a very large
number of people earning minimum wage; we have an unemployment rate
that, while trending downward, is still too high, abetted by continued
inflows of job seekers from less-promising sections of the country. But
I’ll bet you that those who constantly enumerate our deficiencies and
are given to habitual Texas-bashing would give their right—or should I
say, left—arms to have Texas’ record of robust long-term job creation
instead of the anemic employment growth of other megastates such as
California and New York. Or even the job formation record of many other
countries! The following chart shows that over the past two decades,
the rate of employment growth in Texas has exceeded that of the euro
zone and its two anchors, Germany and France, as well as that of two
natural-resource-intensive countries with populations comparable to
Texas’, Canada and Australia.
Now, is all this just
prototypical Texas brag, or are there lessons the nation can learn from
the success that is enjoyed here? Texans are hardly given to modesty,
but I believe there are some undeniable lessons being imparted here.
One lesson I draw from
comparative state data is that monetary policy is a necessary but
insufficient tonic for economic recovery. The Fed has made money cheap
and abundant for the entire country. The citizens of Texas and the
Eleventh Federal Reserve District operate under the same monetary
policy as do our fellow Americans. We have the same mortgage rates and
pay the same rates of interest on commercial and consumer loans, and
our businesses borrow at the same interest rates as their brethren
elsewhere in the country. Which raises an important question: If
monetary policy is the same here as everywhere else in the United
States, why does Texas outperform the other states?
The answer is no doubt
complicated by the fact that Texas is blessed with a comparatively
great amount of nature’s gifts, a high concentration of military
installations and what some claim are other “unfair” advantages.
But many of these
“unfair” advantages are man-made: They derive from a deliberate
approach by state and local authorities to enact business-friendly
regulations and fiscal policy. For example, if you examine the
differences between Texas and two states that have been underperforming
for a prolonged period—California and New York—you will note that
these former power states have less-flexible labor rules. Due to local
taxes, differences in zoning practices and myriad other factors, the
cost of housing and the overall cost of living in California and New
York are significantly higher than they are here. And due to
differences in policies governing education, the scores measuring
middle-school students’ proficiency in math are lower in both
California and New York than they are in Texas, and in reading, are
lower in California and only slightly higher in New York.[5]
Taken together, these
factors, alongside whatever natural advantages we may enjoy (though it
is hard to compete with the physical beauty of California and the Great
Lakes region or the cultural splendor of New York), affect where firms
choose to locate and hire and where people choose to raise their
families and seek jobs.
I would argue that an
additional factor favors Texas: We have a Legislature that under both
Democratic and Republican governors has over time deliberately crafted
laws and regulations, and tax and spending regimes, encouraging
business formation and job creation.
Just last month,
Fairfield, Calif.-based vehicle reseller Copart Inc. announced that it
will move its headquarters to Texas, citing “greater operational
efficiencies.”[6]
The CEO for the owner of Hardee’s and Carl’s Jr. restaurants, Andy
Puzder, claims it takes six months to two years to secure permits in
California to build a new Carl’s Jr., whereas in Texas, it takes six
weeks. These two anecdotes from California alone clearly illustrate
that firms and jobs will go to where it is easiest to do business—not
where it is less convenient and more costly.
Both state and federal
authorities need to bear this in mind as they plot changes in the
fiscal and regulatory policy needed to restore the job-creating engine
of America. As an official of the Federal Reserve charged with making
monetary policy for the country as a whole, I am constantly mindful
that investment and job-creating capital is free to roam not only
within the United States, but to any place on earth where it will earn
the best risk-adjusted return. If other countries with stable
governments offer more attractive tax and regulatory environments,
capital that would otherwise go to creating jobs in the U.S.A. will
migrate abroad, just as intra-U.S. investment is migrating to Texas.
Thus, even if one were
to somehow have 100 percent certainty about the future course of
Federal Reserve policy and be completely comfortable with it, without
greater clarity about the future course of fiscal and regulatory policy
and whether that policy will be competitive in a globalized world,
job-creating investment in the U.S. will remain restrained and our
great economic potential will remain unrealized.
I pull no punches
here: We have been thrown way off course by congresses populated by
generations of Democrats and Republicans who failed the nation by not
budgeting ways to cover the costs of their munificent spending with
adequate revenue streams. The thrust of the political debate is now—and
must continue to be—how to right the listing fiscal ship and put it
back on a course that encourages job formation and gets the economy
steaming again toward ever-greater prosperity. No amount of monetary
accommodation can substitute for the need for responsible hands to take
ahold of the fiscal helm. Indeed, if we at the Fed were to abandon our
wits and seek to do so by inflating away the debts and unfunded
liabilities of Congress, we would only become accomplices to scuttling
the economy.
I was in Mexico last
week. Mexico has many problems, not the least of which is declining oil
production, low school graduation rates and drug-induced violence. But
on the fiscal front, the country is outperforming the United States.
Mexico’s government has developed and implemented better macroeconomic
policy than has the U.S. government.
Mexico’s economy
contracted sharply during the global downturn, with real gross domestic
product (GDP) plummeting 6.2 percent in 2009. But growth roared back,
up 5.5 percent in 2010 and 3.9 percent in 2011, with output reaching
its prerecession peak after 12 quarters—three quarters sooner than in
the U.S. Mexico’s industrial production passed its prerecession peak at
the end of 2010; ours has yet to do so.
Now hold on to your
seats: Mexico actually has a federal budget! We haven’t had one for
almost three years. Furthermore, the Mexican Congress has imposed a
balanced-budget rule and the discipline to go with it, so that even
with the deviation from balance allowed under emergencies, Mexico ran a
budget deficit of only 2.5 percent in 2011, compared with 8.7 percent
in the U.S. Mexico’s national debt totals 27 percent of GDP; in the
U.S., the debt-to-GDP ratio computed on a comparable basis was 99
percent in 2011 and is projected to be 106 percent in 2012. Imagine
that: The country that many Americans look down upon and consider
“undeveloped” is now more fiscally responsible and is growing faster
than the United States. What does that say about the fiscal rectitude
of the U.S. Congress?
Here is the point: As
demonstrated by the relative and continued, inexorable outperformance
by Texas—which is affected by the same monetary policy as are all of
the other 49 states—the key to harnessing the monetary accommodation
provided by the Fed lies in the hands of our fiscal and regulatory
authorities, the Congress working with the executive branch. As
demonstrated by the fiscal posture of Mexico, a nation can effect
budgetary discipline and still have growth.
One might draw two lessons here.
The first comes from
Germany’s finance minister, Wolfgang Schäuble, who from my perspective
was spot on when he said, “If you want more private demand, you have to
take people’s angst away” by having responsible and disciplined fiscal
and regulatory policy.[7] Clearly, there is less angst involved in conducting business in Texas.
The second is a
broader, macroeconomic truism: that fiscal and regulatory policy either
complements monetary policy or retards its utility as a propellant for
job creation. Mexico is proof positive that good fiscal policy
enhances the effectiveness of thoughtfully conducted monetary policy,
which is what the Banco de México—whose independence, incidentally, was
enshrined by a constitutional amendment in 1994—has delivered under
its single mandate of inflation control and by applying the tool of
inflation targeting.
I should be injecting
some levity into the event, though it is hard to do so when one talks
about our feckless fiscal authorities. But there are witty people who
have found a way to do so. Take a look at this parody of Congress that
my staff found on YouTube: www.youtube.com/watch?v=Li0no7O9zmE.
There you have the
prevailing modus operandi of our fiscal authorities: pass the bill
rather than the American dream to our children. What a sad tale!
You asked me to talk
about the economy. In a nutshell, my answer is this: Monetary policy
provides the fuel for the economic engine that is the United States. We
have filled the gas tank and then some. And yet businesses will not
use that fuel to a degree necessary to realize our job-creating
potential and create a better world for the successor generation of
Americans until Congress, working with the executive branch, does the
responsible thing and pulls together a tax, spending and regulatory
program that will induce businesses to step on the accelerator and
engage the transmission mechanism of job creation so they and the
consumers they create through employment can drive our economy forward.
About the Author
Richard W. Fisher is president and CEO of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
No comments:
Post a Comment