Michael Spence
Michael Spence, a Nobel laureate in economics, is currently Chairman of the Commission on Growth and Development, an international body charged with charting opportunities for global economic growt…Full profile
Tradable Prosperity
CommentsMILAN
– The global economy is experiencing a major growth challenge. Many
advanced countries are attempting to revive sustainable growth in the
face of a decelerating global economy. But the challenges across
countries are not the same. In particular, the tradable and non-tradable
parts of a range of economies differ in important ways.
CommentsIn
the non-tradable sector (60-70% of the economy in advanced countries),
the main growth inhibitors are weak demand, as in the United States
following the financial crisis, and structural and competitive
impediments to productivity, as in Japan. In the tradable sector, growth
depends on a country’s productivity relative to incomes and
competitiveness. At the global level, there can also be a shortage of
aggregate demand on the tradable side.
CommentsThe
Nobel laureate economist Robert Solow has shown that growth comes from
three sources: the working population, capital investment, and
technological progress. A growing young population helps to maintain
fiscal balance and ensure intergenerational equity, but it does not by
itself increase incomes. On the other hand, economic growth below the
sum of growth in the working population and the labor-saving part of
technological change fuels unemployment.
CommentsDeveloping
countries, once they enter rapid-growth mode, generate growth from
capital deepening via investment, in a sense making up for past
underinvestment. And it is possible for advanced countries to fall
behind by under-investing, particularly in the public sector, relying
instead on less sustainable debt-fueled means of generating demand. So a
legitimate part of a strategy to restore growth is investment.
CommentsBut,
as Solow noted, investment has its limits, owing to diminishing
marginal returns. Often, these limits are not binding, but, once capital
deepening is exhausted, technological progress, which makes inputs more
productive in creating final value, is the long-run driver of growth.
CommentsThe
challenge is to apply these insights in a world characterized by global
economic interdependence, major imbalances, and a worsening growth and
employment problem. It is a world in which economies are connected
directly in the tradable sector of the global economy, and indirectly
through the demand and employment linkages between the tradable and
non-tradable sectors of individual economies.
CommentsIn
the short run, the non-tradable sector is, by definition, subject to
domestic-demand constraints. A shortfall in non-tradable demand
inevitably limits growth on that side of the economy.
CommentsGovernment
can, of course, bridge the gap via deficit spending (preferably focused
on employment-generating investment that enhances future growth). But
the advanced countries are, to varying degrees, fiscally constrained by
relatively high and rising public debt, largely owing to fiscal
imbalances that were hidden from view until defective growth models
broke down in the crisis of 2008.
CommentsJust
how fiscally constrained these countries are remains subject to debate.
Italy and Spain are clearly constrained by the absence of private
capital in their respective sovereign-debt markets, with rising yields
threatening their fiscal stability and reform programs. They need the
eurozone core and the International Monetary Fund as temporary lenders
of last resort until they restore policy credibility and regain
investors’ confidence.
CommentsThe
US sovereign-debt market shows no similar evidence of having reached a
limit yet. But bond markets do not issue many early warning signals:
witness the sudden run-up of yields in Italy and Spain a year ago.
CommentsThe
more complex growth issues have to do with the tradable part of the
global economy, where global aggregate demand – and the derived demand
that lands in various places in global supply or value-added chains – is
the target of competition. Total demand and its growth do matter, but
so does market share. Given the growth patterns across advanced and
developing countries prior to the crisis, and then the large negative
shock, it is likely that there is a shortfall of tradable global
aggregate demand, impeding an important component of global growth.
CommentsBut,
for individual economies, relative productivity versus income levels
determines the share of global tradable aggregate demand that is
accessible. Unlike the non-tradable side of the economy, the domestic
component of global tradable demand is not an absolute constraint on
growth; nor is the rate of growth of global tradable demand an absolute
constraint, given the possibility of increasing share.
CommentsOf
course, not everyone can gain share at the same time. Fortunately, if
countries increase productivity with the aim of boosting relative
productivity and growth potential on the tradable side, this will
increase incomes and accelerate the growth of global aggregate demand.
It may look like a zero-sum game, but it is not.
CommentsWhen
incomes get significantly out of line with productivity levels (as they
have recently), reviving growth requires resetting the terms of trade,
which can be done with exchange rates, whether managed or set by
markets. In the eurozone, where countries with competitiveness problems
do not have the exchange-rate adjustment mechanism, restrained income
growth and productivity-boosting reforms are probably needed, as was the
case in Germany between 2000 and 2006, and now in several southern
European countries.
CommentsWhat
is true for countries on the tradable side is also true for workers,
who are differentially affected by the evolution of global supply
chains. The efficient integration of global supply chains has created
employment opportunities in developing countries and in the higher
value-added sectors of advanced countries. But it has also reduced
employment options for a subset of middle-income people in the tradable
sectors of advanced economies.
CommentsMany
countries are struggling to adapt their growth patterns to the new
challenges they face in a slowing global economy. To be effective and
properly targeted, policies need to include an accurate diagnosis of
growth potential and impediments in both the tradable and non-tradable
parts of the economy. Focusing on one (say, the competitiveness problem
in the tradable sector) to the exclusion of the other (perhaps a serious
non-tradable demand shortfall or stagnant absolute productivity) will
not be enough.
No comments:
Post a Comment